Pacandus

 Bartolommeo Pacca

 St. Pachomius

 George Michael Pachtler

 Pacificus

 Bl. Pacificus of Ceredano

 St. Pacificus of San Severino

 Lucas Pacioli

 Diocese of Paderborn

 Juan de Padilla

 Diocese of Padua

 University of Padua

 Paganism

 Mario Pagano

 Ven. Anthony Page

 Antoine Pagi

 Santes Pagnino

 Religious Painting

 Pakawá Indians

 Palæography

 Palæontology

 Juan de Palafox y Mendoza

 Ven. Thomas Palasor

 Rhenish Palatinate

 Palatini

 Prefecture Apostolic of Palawan

 Diocese of Palencia

 Paleopolis

 Gabriele Paleotti

 Archdiocese of Palermo

 University of Palermo

 Diocese of Palestrina

 Giovanni Pierluigi da Palestrina

 Frederick Apthorp Paley

 Pall

 Andrea Palladio

 St. Palladius

 Palladius

 Pietro Sforza Pallavicino

 Pallium

 Ven. Vincent Mary Pallotti

 Palma Vecchio

 William Palmer

 Domenico Palmieri

 Luigi Palmieri

 Palm in Christian Symbolism

 Palm Sunday

 Palmyra

 Francisco Palou

 Paltus

 Peter Paludanus

 Pamelius

 Diocese of Pamiers

 St. Pammachius

 St. Pamphilus of Cæsarea

 Diocese of Pamplona

 Republic and Diocese of Panama

 Pandects

 Pandulph

 Panemotichus

 Pange Lingua Gloriosi

 Francesco Panigarola

 Arnold Pannartz and Konrad Sweinheim

 Pano Indians

 Panopolis

 Panpsychism

 Pantænus

 St. Pantaleon

 Pantheism

 Onofrio Panvinio

 Gregorio Panzani

 Ven. Angelo Paoli

 Papacy

 Pápago Indians

 Papal Arbitration

 Papal Elections

 Paphnutius

 Paphos

 St. Papias

 Bernardus Papiensis

 Nicholas Papini

 Parables

 Parabolani

 Theophrastus Paracelsus

 Paraclete

 François Para du Phanjas

 Parætonium

 Paraguay

 Books of Paralipomenon

 Diocese of Parahyba

 Parallelism

 Psycho-Physical Parallelism

 Paralus

 Diocese of Paraná

 Parasceve

 Paray-le-Monial

 Ignace-Gaston Pardies

 Pardons of Brittany

 Ambroise Paré

 Francisco Pareja

 Parents

 Diocese of Parenzo-Pola

 Giuseppe Parini

 Paris

 University of Paris

 Alexis-Paulin Paris

 Gaston-Bruno-Paulin Paris

 Matthew Paris

 Parish

 Parium

 Abbey of the Park

 Anthony Parkinson

 Parlais

 Filippo Parlatore

 Diocese of Parma

 Antoine-Augustin Parmentier

 Il Parmigiano

 Parnassus

 Parochial Mass

 Parœcopolis

 Dominique Parrenin

 Parsis

 Partnership

 Paolo Paruta

 Blaise Pascal

 St. Pascal Baylon

 Pasch or Passover

 Pope Paschal I

 Pope Paschal II

 Paschal III

 Paschal Candle

 Paschal Tide

 St. Paschasius

 St. Paschasius Radbertus

 Carlo Passaglia

 Diocese of Passau

 Ven. Joseph Passerat

 Domenico Passignano

 Domenico Passionei

 Passionists

 Passion Music

 Commemoration of the Passion of Christ

 Passion Offices

 Devotion to the Passion of Jesus Christ

 Passion of Jesus Christ in the Four Gospels

 Passion Plays

 Passions

 Passion Sunday

 Passiontide

 Passos

 Louis Pasteur

 Diocese of Pasto

 Pastor

 Crusade of the Pastoureaux

 Patagonia

 Patara

 Paten

 Ven. William Patenson

 Mental Pathology

 Coventry Patmore

 Patmos

 Patras

 Patriarch

 Patriarch and Patriarchate

 Patrician Brothers

 St. Patrick

 Francis Xavier Patrizi

 Patrology

 Feast of the Patronage of Our Lady

 Patron and Patronage

 Patron Saints

 Diocese of Patti

 St. Paul

 Pope Paul I

 Pope Paul II

 Pope Paul III

 Pope Paul IV

 Pope Paul V

 St. Paula

 Johannes Pauli

 Paulicians

 St. Paulinus

 St. Paulinus, Bishop of Nola

 St. Paulinus II, Patriarch of Aquileia

 Paulinus a S. Bartholomaeo

 Paulinus of Pella

 Paulists

 Paul of Burgos

 Paul of Middelburg

 Paul of Samosata

 St. Paul of the Cross

 St. Paul the Hermit

 St. Paul the Simple

 Paulus Diaconus

 Paulus Venetus

 Diocese of Pavia

 Nicolas Pavillon

 Pax

 Pax in the Liturgy

 Mariano Payeras

 Peter Pázmány

 Peace Congresses

 War of the Peasants (1524-25)

 Peba Indians

 John Pecham

 Reginald Pecock

 Pectoral

 Pectorale

 Pednelissus

 Pedro de Cordova

 Pelagia

 Pope Pelagius I

 Pope Pelagius II

 Pelagius and Pelagianism

 Ambrose Pelargus

 Paul Pelisson-Fontanier

 Pella

 Pierre-Joseph Pelletier

 Silvio Pellico

 Guillaume Pellissier

 Diocese of Pelotas

 Théophile-Jules Pelouze

 Madeleine de La Peltrie

 Pelusium

 Diocese of Pembroke

 Francisco Peña

 Penal Laws

 Luis Ignatius Peñalver y Cardenas

 Penance

 Henry Pendleton

 Penelakut Indians

 Los Hermanos Penitentes

 Penitential Canons

 Penitential Orders

 Confraternities of Penitents

 Diocese of Penne and Atri

 Pennsylvania

 Penobscot Indians

 Ecclesiastical Pension

 Pentacomia

 Pentapolis

 Pentateuch

 Feast of Pentecost (of the Jews)

 Diocese of Peoria

 Peoria Indians

 Pepin the Short

 John Percy

 Peregrinus

 Benedict Pereira

 Juan Perez

 Ginés Pérez de Hita

 Christian and Religious Perfection

 Pergamus

 Perge

 Giovanni Battista Pergolesi

 Pericui Indians

 Diocese of Périgueux

 Periodi

 Periodical Literature

 Perjury

 Franz Michael Permaneder

 Joseph Maria Pernter

 Religious of Perpetual Adoration

 Religious of the Perpetual Adoration

 Sisters of the Perpetual Adoration

 Perpetual Adorers of the Blessed Sacrament

 Sisters of Our Lady of Perpetual Help

 Our Lady of Perpetual Succour

 St. Perpetuus

 Diocese of Perpignan

 Adolphe Perraud

 Charles Perrault

 Claude Perrault

 Henri Perreyve

 Giovanni Perrone

 Stephen Joseph Perry

 Persecution

 Coptic Persecutions

 Final Perseverance

 Persia

 Ignatius Persico

 Person

 Ecclesiastical Person

 Personality

 Robert Persons

 Diocese of Perth

 Publius Helvius Pertinax

 Peru

 Archdiocese of Perugia

 Perugino (Pietro Vannucci)

 Baldassare Peruzzi

 Diocese of Pesaro

 Pescennius Niger

 Tilmann Pesch

 Diocese of Pescia

 Pessimism

 Pessinus

 Pestalozzi and Pestalozzianism

 Denis Pétau

 St. Peter

 Epistles of St. Peter

 Sarah Peter

 Sts. Peter Baptist and Twenty-five Companions

 Peterborough Abbey

 Diocese of Peterborough

 Bl. Peter Canisius

 Peter Cantor

 Peter Cellensis

 St. Peter Chrysologus

 St. Peter Claver

 Peter Comestor

 St. Peter Damian

 Peter de Blois

 Peter de Honestis

 St. Peter de Regalado

 Peter de Vinea

 Bl. Peter Faber

 St. Peter Fourier

 Peter Fullo

 St. Peter Gonzalez

 Bl. Peter Igneus

 Peter Lombard (2)

 Bl. Pierre-Louis-Marie Chanel (1)

 Peter Mongus

 St. Peter Nolasco

 St. Peter of Alcántara

 St. Peter of Alexandria

 Peter of Aquila

 St. Peter of Arbues

 Peter of Auvergne

 Peter of Bergamo

 Peter of Poitiers

 St. Peter of Sebaste

 St. Peter of Verona

 Peterspence

 Gerlac Peterssen

 Peter the Hermit

 St. Peter Urseolus

 Petinessus

 Matthieu Petit-Didier

 Petitions to the Holy See

 Petra

 Francesco Petrarch

 Family of Petre

 Petrobrusians

 St. Petronilla

 St. Petronius

 Diocese of Petropolis

 Ottavio dei Petrucci

 Petrus Alfonsus

 Petrus Bernardinus

 Petrus Diaconus

 Petrus de Natalibus

 Petun Nation

 George von Peuerbach

 Conrad Peutinger

 William Peyto

 Pez

 Franz Pfanner

 Johannes Pfefferkorn

 Adolf Pfister

 Julius von Pflug

 Pforta

 Phacusa

 Pharao

 Pharbætus

 Pharisees

 Pharsalus

 Phaselis

 Phasga

 Phenomenalism

 Philadelphia

 Archdiocese of Philadelphia

 Philanthropinism

 St. Philastrius

 Philemon

 St. Philip the Apostle

 Volume 13

 Philip II (Augustus)

 Philip II

 Philip IV

 St. Philip Benizi

 St. Philip of Jesus

 Philip of the Blessed Trinity

 Philippi (1)

 Philippi (2)

 Epistle to the Philippians

 Philippine Islands

 Philippopolis (1)

 Philippopolis (2)

 St. Philip Romolo Neri

 Peter Philips

 Philip the Arabian

 Philistines

 Robert Phillip

 George Phillips

 Philo Judæus

 Philomelium

 St. Philomena

 Philosophy

 Philoxenus

 Phocæa

 Phœnicia

 Photinus

 Photius of Constantinople

 Phylacteries

 History of Physics

 Physiocrats

 Physiologus

 Diocese of Piacenza

 Giambattista Pianciani

 Giovanni da Pianô Carpine

 Piatto Cardinalizio

 Diocese of Piauhy

 Diocese of Piazza Armerina

 Giuseppe Piazzi

 Ven. John Pibush

 Jean Picard

 Alessandro Piccolomini

 Jacopo Piccolomini-Ammannati

 Pichler

 Vitus Pichler

 Ven. Thomas Pickering

 Bernardine a Piconio

 François Picquet

 Louis-Edouard-Désiré Pie

 Piedmont

 Peter Piel

 Pie Pelicane, Jesu, Domine

 Pierius

 Bl. Pierre de Castelnau

 Pierre de Maricourt

 Jean Pierron

 Philippe Pierson

 Pietism

 Albert (Pigghe) Pighius

 Ven. Giuseppe Maria Pignatelli

 Ven. William Pike

 Nuestra Señora Del Pilar

 Pontius Pilate

 Ven. Thomas Pilchard

 Pilgrimage of Grace

 Pilgrimages

 Piligrim

 Pillar of Cloud

 Pima Indians

 Pinara

 Diocese of Pinar del Rio

 Ippolito Pindemonte

 John de Pineda

 Diocese of Pinerolo

 Alexandre Guy Pingré

 Mattheus Pinna da Encarnaçao

 Fernão Mendes Pinto

 Pinturicchio

 Martín Alonso Pinzón

 Sebastiano del Piombo

 St. Pionius

 Pious Fund of the Californias

 Pious Society of Missions

 Giambattista Piranesi

 Ernricus Pirhing

 Pirkheimer

 Piro Indians

 Archdiocese of Pisa

 University of Pisa

 Council of Pisa

 Piscataway Indians

 Piscina

 Charles Constantine Pise

 Pisidia

 Synod of Pistoia

 Diocese of Pistoia and Prato

 Johann Pistorius

 Pierre Pithou

 Joseph Pitoni

 Jean-Baptiste-François Pitra

 John Pitts

 Diocese of Pittsburg

 Pityus

 Pope St. Pius I

 Pope Pius II

 Pope Pius III

 Pope Pius IV

 Pope St. Pius V

 Pope Pius VI

 Pope Pius VII

 Pope Pius VIII

 Pope Pius IX

 Pope Pius X

 Piusverein

 Francisco Pizarro

 Galla Placidia

 St. Placidus

 Plagues of Egypt

 Plain Chant

 Henry Beaufort Plantagenet

 Christophe Plantin

 Plants in the Bible

 Diocese of Plasencia

 Bartolomeo Platina

 Plato and Platonism

 Pierre-Guillaume-Frédéric Le Play

 Plegmund

 Plenarium

 Plenary Council

 Joseph-Octave Plessis

 Georgius Gemistus Plethon

 Diocese of Plock

 Charles Plowden

 Edmund Plowden

 Francis Plowden

 Robert Plowden

 Thomas Plowden

 Thomas Percy Plowden

 Charles Plumier

 Ven. Oliver Plunket

 Pluscarden Priory

 Diocese of Plymouth

 Plymouth Brethren

 Pneumatomachi

 Hebrew Poetry of the Old Testament

 Giovanni Francesco Poggio Bracciolini

 Diocese of Poggio Mirteto

 Pogla

 Diocese of Poitiers

 Poland

 John Bede Polding

 Reginald Pole

 Polemonium

 Giovanni Poleni

 Poles in the United States

 Diocese of Policastro

 Melchior de Polignac

 Lancelot Politi

 Politian

 Science of Political Economy

 Antonio and Piero Benci Pollajuolo

 Marco Polo

 Polybotus

 St. Polycarp

 Polycarpus

 Polyglot Bibles

 Polystylum

 Polytheism

 Pomaria

 Marquis de Pombal

 Pomerania

 Pompeiopolis

 Pietro Pomponazzi

 John Ponce

 Juan Ponce de León

 Joseph Anthony de la Rivière Poncet

 Archdiocese of Pondicherry

 Pontefract Priory

 Pope St. Pontian

 Pontifical Colleges

 Pontificale

 Pontificalia

 Pontifical Mass

 Abbey of Pontigny

 Pontius Carbonell

 Diocese of Pontremoli

 Pontus

 Pools in Scripture

 Diocese of Poona

 Care of Poor by the Church

 Little Sisters of the Poor

 Poor Brothers of St. Francis Seraphicus

 Poor Catholics

 Sisters of the Poor Child Jesus

 Poor Clares

 Poor Handmaids of Jesus Christ

 Poor Laws

 Sisters of the Poor of St. Francis

 Poor Servants of the Mother of God

 Archdiocese of Popayán

 Alexander Pope

 Pope

 Election of the Popes

 Chronological Lists of Popes

 The List of Popes

 St. Poppo

 Popular Devotions

 Theories of Population

 Giovanni Antonio Pordenone

 Odoric of Pordenone

 Ven. Thomas Pormort

 Porphyreon

 St. Porphyrius

 Serafino Porrecta

 Carlo Porta

 Giacomo della Porta

 Diocese of Portalegre

 Diocese of Port Augusta

 Archdiocese of Port-au-Prince

 Porter

 Francis Porter

 George Porter

 Portiuncula

 Diocese of Portland

 Diocese of Port Louis

 Archdiocese of Porto Alegre

 Diocese of Porto Alegre

 Diocese of Porto and Santa-Rufina

 Archdiocese of Port of Spain

 Porto Rico

 Diocese of Portoviejo

 Portraits of the Apostles

 Port-Royal

 Diocese of Portsmouth

 Portugal

 Portuguese East Africa

 Portuguese West Africa

 Diocese of Port Victoria

 Positivism

 Demoniacal Possession

 Antonius Possevinus

 St. Possidius

 Postcommunion

 Ven. Nicholas Postgate

 Postulant

 Postulation

 Potawatomi Indians

 Robert Joseph Pothier

 Jean-François-Albert du Pouget

 Thomas Pounde

 Nicolas Poussin

 Poverty

 Poverty and Pauperism

 Ven. Philip Powel

 William Poynter

 Andreas Pozzo

 Diocese of Pozzuoli

 Jean-Martin de Prades

 Jerome de Prado

 Praelatus Nullius

 Pragmatic Sanction

 Pragmatism

 Archdiocese of Prague

 University of Prague

 Praxeas

 Praxedes and Pudentiana

 George Pray

 Prayer

 Prayer-Books

 Feast of the Prayer of Christ

 Preacher Apostolic

 Order of Preachers

 Preadamites

 Prebend

 Precaria

 Precedence

 Precentor

 Canonical Precept

 Precious Blood

 Archconfraternity of the Most Precious Blood

 Congregation of the Most Precious Blood

 Congregations of the Precious Blood

 Count Humbert-Guillaume de Precipiano

 Preconization

 Predestinarianism

 Predestination

 Preface

 Prefect Apostolic

 Prelate

 Joseph Henri Marie de Prémare

 Premonstratensian Canons

 Abbey of Prémontré

 Presbyterianism

 Presbytery

 Prescription

 Presence of God

 Order of the Presentation

 Religious Congregations of the Presentation

 Right of Presentation

 Presentation Brothers

 Congregation of the Presentation of Mary

 Feast of the Presentation of the Blessed Virgin Mary

 Prester John

 Thomas Preston

 Thomas Scott Preston

 Presumption

 Presumption (in Canon Law)

 Pretorium

 Pride

 Priene

 Priest

 Assistant Priest

 High Priest

 Priesthood

 Confraternities of Priests

 Priests' Communion League

 Priests' Eucharistic League

 Primacy

 Primate

 Prime

 The Primer

 Primicerius

 Sts. Primus and Felician

 Diocese of Prince Albert

 Prior

 Prioress

 Priory

 St. Prisca

 Priscianus

 Priscillianism

 Prisons

 Ecclesiastical Prisons

 Privilege

 Ecclesiastical Privileges

 Faltonia Proba

 Probabilism

 Marcus Aurelius Probus

 Roman Processional

 Processions

 Sts. Processus and Martinian

 St. Proclus

 Proconnesus

 Procopius of Caesarea

 Adelaide Anne Procter

 Procurator

 Religious Profession

 Divine Promise (in Scripture)

 Promotor Fidei

 Promulgation

 Proof

 Sacred Congregation of Propaganda

 Society for the Propagation of the Faith

 Property

 Property Ecclesiastical

 Ecclesiastical Property in the United States

 Prophecy

 Prophecy, Prophet, and Prophetess

 Proprium

 Franz Isidor Proschko

 Proselyte

 Prose or Sequence

 Karl Proske

 Tiro Prosper of Aquitaine

 Protectorate of Missions

 Protectories

 Protestant Episcopal Church in the United States of America

 Protestantism

 Prothonotary Apostolic

 Protocol

 Protopope

 Sts. Protus and Hyacinth

 Father Prout

 Léon Abel Provancher

 Book of Proverbs

 Congregations of Providence

 Diocese of Providence

 Divine Providence

 Ecclesiastical Province

 Provincial

 Provincial Council

 Canonical Provision

 Statute of Provisors

 Provost

 Prudence

 Aurelius Clemens Prudentius

 Prudentius

 Prüm

 Prusias ad Hypium

 Prussia

 Diocese of Przemysl

 Diocese of Przemysl, Sambor, and Sanok

 Psalms

 Alphabetic Psalms

 Psalterium

 Nicholas Psaume

 Michael Psellus

 Psychology

 Psychotherapy

 Ptolemais

 Ptolemais (Saint-Jean d'Acre)

 Ptolemy the Gnostic

 Publican

 Public Honesty (Decency)

 Pueblo Indians

 Pierre Puget

 George Ellis Pugh

 Augustus Welby Northmore Pugin

 Victor-Alexandre Puiseux

 Casimir Pulaski

 Diocese of Pulati

 St. Pulcheria

 Luigi Pulci

 Robert Pullen

 Pulpit

 Capital Punishment

 Diocese of Puno

 John Baptist Purcell

 Purgatorial Societies

 Purgatory

 St. Patrick's Purgatory

 Purim

 Puritans

 Pusey and Puseyism

 Pustet

 Putative Marriage

 Erycius Puteanus

 Joseph Putzer

 Pierre Puvis de Chavannes

 Puyallup Indians

 Johann Ladislaus von Oberwart Pyrker

 Pyrrhonism

 Pythagoras and Pythagoreanism

 Pyx

Science of Political Economy


SCIENCE OF POLITICAL ECONOMY (ECONOMICS).


I. DEFINITIONS

Political economy (Greek, oikonomia — the management of a household or family, politike — pertaining to the state) or economics (ta oikonomika — the art of household management) is the social science which treats of man's activities in providing the material means to satisfy his wants.

Economy originally meant the management and regulation of the resources of the household; that is, of the immediate family with its slaves and dependents. Political economy originally meant the management of the household of the State. It was so used as late as Adam Smith (Wealth of Nations, 1776), who defined it thus:


The sum of the efforts and activities of the members of the household in acquiring the means to satisfy their wants may be designated as the economy of the household. Where a household is not economically self-sufficing, that is, where households are economically interdependent, we have a broader economy. Where this interdependence is state- or nation-wide, there exists a national economy or political economy.

The term political economy is used in yet a third sense. It is the name of the science which treats of this nation-wide complexus of economic activities.


II. METHOD

Deductive. English economists in the early part of the nineteenth century, beginning with Malthus and Ricardo, hoped to establish a science of political economy independent of the art of the statesman, which would vie with the natural sciences in the exactness of its conclusions. They narrowed the field as conceived by Adam Smith by variously defining political economy as the science of wealth, the science of value, or the science of exchanges. But along with this narrowing of the field and the attainment of scientific precision in the use of terms went a divorce of their science from the economic realities of life. Their method was strictly deductive. Beginning with three or four principles for which they claimed universal validity, they proceeded to deduce a complete system without further appeal to the facts of life. These English writers, known as the Classical or Orthodox School, held that political economy must not concern itself with ethical or practical considerations. To do so, in their opinion, would degrade it to an art, for the science of political economy was concerned merely with the explanation of the causal relations existing among economic phenomena. It was their business as economists simply to explain the existing economic system not to defend or condemn it, nor to show how it might be replaced by a better one. To them good and bad were concepts which concerned moralists and not economists.

Inductive. In opposition to this narrow and non-ethical view of the Classical School, there arose in Germany in the middle of the nineteenth century, the Historical School, holding that political economy is an inductive and an ethical science. They derided the abstractions of the Orthodox School, some extremists even going so far as to contend that the time was not yet ripe for a science of political economy. The business of their generation, they held, was to gather from observation and history and to classify the economic facts upon which future economists might construct a science.

Deductive and Inductive. After a bitter struggle of half a century the opposition between the schools has almost disappeared, and it is now generally recognized that the economist must use both the deductive and the inductive methods, using now one predominantly and now the other, according to the nature of the problem upon which he happens to be engaged. The best usage of the present time is to make political economy an ethical science, that is, to make it include a discussion of what ought to be in the economic world as well as what is. This has all along been the practice of Catholic writers. Some of them even go so far as to make political economy a branch of ethics and not an independent science. (See Devas, "Principles of Political Economy".) For a further discussion of the relationship between the two sciences, see .


III. SCOPE

For purposes of exposition the field of political economy is often divided into four parts: production, consumption, distribution, and exchange. Some authors omit one or another of these divisions, treating its problems under the remaining heads.

Production. The department of production is concerned with the creation of wealth through the united efforts of land, labor, and capital. The creation of wealth involves the bringing into existence of utilities, that is, of capacities to satisfy wants. Utilities are created by changes in form of goods, or in their location, or by keeping them from a time of less demand to a time of greater demand.

Consumption. Consumption is concerned with the destruction of utilities in goods. It is the utilization of wealth, the carrying out of the purpose for which wealth is produced.

Distribution. The department of distribution considers the manner in which the wealth which has been produced is divided among the agents which have produced it. The shares in distribution are: rent, which is paid to the landlord for the use of the land; wages, which is the return to the labourer; interest, which goes to the capitalist for the use of his capital; and profit, which is the reward of the entrepreneur or undertaker of the business.

Exchange. Finally, exchange has to do with the transfer of ownership of wealth. Under this head are discussed money and credit and international exchanges.

Other Subjects. Outside of these four divisions separate chapters are usually devoted to a consideration of taxation, monopolies, transportation, economic progress, and other problems. Adam Smith and his immediate followers were more closely concerned with the problems of production. Owing to the world's remarkable progress in that direction in the last century, the inequalities of distribution have come more and more into prominence, and this is now the favourite field of the economist.


IV. HISTORY

Ancient. In ancient Greece and Rome there was little likelihood of the emergence of a science of political economy. Their industrial system was founded on slavery, the great estates were for the most part self-sufficient economic units, leaving comparatively little room for commerce, and labour was held in contempt by the thinking element. However, fragmentary discussions on economic subjects, mingled with ethical and political considerations, are to be found. Xenophon has a rather extensive treatment of household economy. Plato, in the "Republic", advocates an ideal communistic State. Aristotle presents a defense of private property, and writes against the taking of interest on the ground that money is barren. He defends warmly the institution of slavery. Among the Romans there was not much originality. We find frequent discussions of the relative merits of large and small farms. Cicero, Pliny the Elder, and other writers deplored the introduction of gold as a medium of exchange and preferred the age of barter. Seneca wrote upon the ethics of political economy and pleaded for the simple life.

Patristic Writers. Under Christian influence labour, which had been held in contempt by the Pagans, came to be respected and honoured. The rigors of slavery were mitigated and the milder form of serfdom grew up, which later gave way to free labour. The Roman law had insisted on the rights of property; the early Fathers on the other hand, insisted on the rights of man. Some even went to the extent of advocating a system of communism as the ideal state, merely tolerating private property. "The soil," says St. Ambrose, "was given to rich and poor in common." St. Gregory the Great, St. Augustine, St. Basil the Great, St. John Chrysostom, and St. Jerome write in similar vein. The taking of usury was universally condemned.

Middle Ages. By the end of the Middle Ages there was developed a complete and systematic economic doctrine. This doctrine differed from modern political economy in two important aspects. In the first place it was made to fit the economic institutions of that day, and would be inadequate if applied to ours; and secondly, the emphasis was placed upon the ethically desirable rather than upon the actually existent, However, this latter distinction is now very much less marked than it was in the first half of the nineteenth century. Such questions as property, wealth, consumption, value, price, money, loans, monopoly, and taxation were treated in detail. To the medieval theologian, the "just price" of an article included enough to pay fair wages to the worker, that is, enough to enable him to maintain the standard of living of his class. In a like manner, a reasonable profit was defended as the wages of the merchant. With certain limitations, the taking of interest for money loans was forbidden. On the other hand, there were certain classes of productive investments, such as the buying of rent-charges, where interest was allowed. Among the writers of the period on economic subjects, St. Thomas Aquinas takes first place. Other writers of importance were Henry of Ghent, Ægidius Colonna, Petrarch, Nicholas Oresme, Bishop of Lisieux who wrote a work on money for his pupil Charles V, and finally St. Antoninus, Archbishop of Florence, and St. Bernardine of Siena.

Mercantile System. In the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries a revolution in industrial activities was taking place which had a profound influence upon the economic literature. The great geographical discoveries, the invention of gunpowder and printing, the decay of feudalism and the rise of modern states, the increase in the supply of the precious metals, and the growing use of credit — all these united to furnish problems for endless discussion. Statesmen, feeling the need of money to support war, adopted various restrictive measures to obtain it. The economic writers who defended these restrictions are usually classed together as the Mercantile School. Sometimes the attempt was made to keep money in the country by prohibiting its exportation or by debasing the coinage. Another way was to encourage the exportation of finished commodities and the importation of raw material in order to secure a balance of trade. Mercantilism reached its highest perfection under Colbert, the Minister of Finance under Louis XIV, and is sometimes referred to as Colbertism. Later imitators of Colbert were less successful, and Mercantilism often degenerated into a system of special privileges and exemptions, without any adequate advantage to the nation. Prominent among the Mercantilist writers were Jean Bodin (d. 1596), Giovanni Botero (d. 1617), Juan Mariana (d. 1623), Antonio Serra (published in 1613), Antoine de Montchrétien (Traité d'économie politique, 1615), who was the originator of the term political economy, and Thomas Mun (d. 1641), author of "England's Treasure by Foreign Trade",

System of Natural Liberty. During the Mercantile period statesmen had interested themselves in industry principally for the purpose of carrying on war; in the following period wars were carried on in the interest of industry and commerce. Under Mercantile influence, the attitude of governments had been decidedly paternalistic. In the eighteenth century those who speak for commerce and industry demand that these be allowed to develop freely, unhampered by the guiding strings of government. In France there grew up a school of economic writers later known as the Physiocrats, who protested against the balance of trade doctrine of the Mercantile School and summed up the duties of the government towards industry and commerce in the famous phrase "laissez faire et laissez passer". They believed in a beneficent "order of nature" which should be allowed free play. To them, agriculture alone was productive. The Physiocrats had been strongly influenced by such English writers as Locke, Petty, and Hume, and they in turn were destined to further influence English political economy.

Adam Smith (1723-90), "the father of political economy" was a result of the combination of both the English and the French currents. His work, "An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations" (1776), gained immediate popularity and exercised profound political influence in the next generation. Smith held that while the individual selfishly seeks his private gain, he is led by an invisible hand to promote the public good, and that since the individual and social interests are identical, the sphere of state action should be narrowed. He thus followed up the attack on the Mercantile system begun by the Physiocrats. He differed from the Physiocrats in making labour as well as land productive. Among the followers of Smith are to be noted Malthus ("Essay on Population", 1798), author of the startling statement that population tends to increase in a geometrical ratio while subsistence tends to increase in an arithmetical ratio, and Ricardo ("Principles of Political Economy and Taxation", 1817), whose name is associated with the differential rent theory, the subsistence theory of wages, and the labour theory of value. Other writers of the English Classical School, who followed closely in the footsteps of Malthus and Ricardo, were James Mill, MacCulloch Senior, and John Stuart Mill. The last named in his later life renounced the individualism of the Orthodox School in favour of socialistic views.

Historical School. About the middle of the nineteenth century there began in Germany under the leadership of Wilhelm Roscher, Karl Knies, and Bruno Hildebrand, a reaction against the Orthodox-English School. These writers insisted on the relativity of economic theory, that is, they did not believe that economic principles, good for all times and places, and all degrees of economic development, could be established. Moreover, they insisted strongly on the need of the study of economic history and upon the ethical and practical character of political economy. They were soon in complete control of the economic teaching of Germany. They differ radically from the Physiocrats and Adam Smith in their repudiation of the doctrine of natural liberty. In fact many of them have gone so far in the opposite direction as to be designated Kathedersozialisten (Professorial Socialists), because of their reliance on state help in accomplishing social reforms.

Austrian School. Since 1871 there has grown up in Austria a group of writers who make of political economy a deductive and psychological science of value. They oppose to the cost-of-production explanation of value of the Classical School, a theory of value based upon marginal utility. It is a well known psychological fact that the utilities of additional units of a commodity to a consumer diminish as the supply increases. Now it is the utility of the last or marginal unit consumed, says the Austrian School, which determines value. Menger, Wieser, Boehm-Bawerk, in Austria, the late W. Stanley Jevons, in England, and J. B. Clark, in America, are the leading representatives of this school.

Socialism. Socialism represents the extreme of reaction against laissez faire or the system of natural liberty of the Physiocrats and Adam Smith. Laissez faire professes to believe in the identity of the interests of the different industrial classes and hence decries the need of restrictive legislation, while socialism emphatically denies that this solidarity exists under our present system and seeks to develop a "class consciousness" among the workers that will overthrow the influence of the dominant class. Economic socialism borrowed the labour theory of value from Ricardo and gave it an ethical interpretation, holding that since labour is the sole producer of wealth, the labourer should receive the entire product. Accordingly, the socialists deny the right of the capitalist to interest and of the landlord to rent, and would make capital and land common property. According to Karl Marx ("Das Kapital", 1867), the founder of so-called scientific socialism, the labourer under the present system does not receive more than a bare subsistence. The "surplus value" which he produces above this amount is appropriated by landlords and capitalists. Another contribution of Marx to socialism is the materialistic conception of history, according to which such factors in history as religion, ethics, and the family, undergo changes corresponding to the changes in the underlying economic organization of which they are a product.

Christian Democracy. The movement which has been gaining ground for the last half century among Christian churches, both Catholic and non-Catholic, to emphasize the importance of religious and moral elements in a healthy economic life, and which protests more or less strongly against laissez faire, is usually designated as Christian Socialism. This name is, however, not well chosen, since none of the so-called Christian socialists hold to the fundamental principle of socialism, namely the abolishment of private ownership in the means of production.

The Protestant writers in this field have naturally lacked an authority which would hold them together. In England their adoption of co-operative associations as a substitute for competition has given them a unity which they have not attained elsewhere.

The Catholic School agrees with the socialists in much of their criticism of the competitive system, but parts company with them by insisting on the place of religion, the family, property, and the employer system in the social scheme. In the matter of state intervention, there are among Catholic writers two general tendencies. The more "liberal" wing, led by such economists as Le Play, Périn, and Victor Brants, would reduce state action to a minimum, while others, looking to Bishop Ketteler, Cardinal Manning, and Count de Mun, would invoke a considerable measure of so-called State socialism. A strong impulse towards unity of effort among Catholics was given by the publication of the encyclicals of Pope Leo XIII, "Rerum Novarum", of 15 May, 1891, and "Graves de Communi", of 18 January, 1901.

In addition to the writers named above, consult: INGRAM, Hist. of Pot. Econ. (London, 1907); CossA, An In-trod. to the Study of Pot. Econ., tr. from the Ital ian by DYER (London, and New York, 1893) (contains an excellent bibliography); KEYNES, The Scope and Method of Pot. Econ. (London and New York, 1904); ASHLEY, An Introd. to Eng. Econ. Hist. and Theory (New York and London, 1894); MAR SHALL, Prin. of Eco nomics (London, 1898); LIBERATORE, Prin. of Pot, Econ., tr. DARING (London and New York, 1891); SEAGER, Introd. to Economics(NewYork, 1908); ELY, Outlines of Economics (New York, 1908); HADLEY, Eco nomics (New York, 1896); NICHOLSON, Prin. of Pot. Econ. (New York and London, 1893- 1901); SELIGMAN, Prin. of Economics (New York,LondonandBom bay, 1905); WALKER, Pot. Econ. (New York, 1888); RYAN, A Living Wage (New York, 1906); PESCH, Lehrbuch der Nationalökonomie (Freiburg and St. Louis, 1905-1909); WAGNER, Grundlegung der politischen Oekonomie (1892-1894); SCHMOLLER, Grun4riss der allgemeinen Volkswirtschaftslehre (Leipzig, 1900-1904); COHN, Grundlegung der Nationaloekonomie (Stuttgart, 1885- 1898); PHI LIPPOVICH, Grundrtss der politischen Oekonomie (Tubingen, 1904); LEROY-BEAULIEU, Traité d'économie politique (Paris, 1910); GIDE, Cours d'économie politique (Paris, 1909); SAY, TrditÍ d'économie politique (Paris, 1803); JANNET, Le Socialisme d'etat et la Réforme Sociale (Paris, 1890); HITZE, Die Arbeiterfrage (Berlin, 1900); ANTOINE, Cours d'économie sociale (Paris, 1899); RATZINOER, Die Volkswirtschaft in ihren sittlichen Grundlagen (Freiburg, 1881); PALGRAVE, Dtcttonary of Pot. Econ. (London and New York, 1894-1899); CONRAD, Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften (Jena, 1890-1894); BRUDER in Staatslexikon (Freiburg and St. Louis, 1889-1897).

FRANK O'HARA